Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY
/
Dispelling the WWII Productivity Myth
Dispelling the WWII Productivity Myth
Jun 23, 2025 5:11 PM

  To fight against the ghost of neoliberalism, a fierce patrol of scholars has recently rediscovered the entrepreneurial state. From the left (Mariana Mazzucato, Dani Rodrik) to the right (Oren Cass and the American Compass group), scholars and journalists are advocating for new industrial policies to address variously perceived “market failures.”

  These authors tend to build their theories, explicitly or implicitly, on what is now an economic history cliché: namely, that much of the postwar development in the United States was indebted to the great research and development (RD) effort expended during World War II. In particular, it is now a commonplace belief that the need to win the war led to the development of a whole range of new technologies and new production methods which then found wide use in peacetime.

  In his new book, The Economic Consequences of US Mobilization for the Second World War, Alexander J. Field of Santa Clara University challenges this narrative. His work demonstrates that the war, in fact, had a negative impact on US productivity—and did not foster a cornucopia of inventions either.

  Field’s work forces us to face the inconvenient truth that, generally speaking, emergencies will tend to reduce productivity, at least in the short and medium term, because they involve shifting human and financial resources from their previous uses to other, different ones. The way factors of production are combined at a certain time is not necessarily the right way: changes, in technology or consumer preferences, induce many, small adjustments every day. The more radical ones, we know, tend to be painful.

  But forcing, for instance, workers who are used to making automobiles to make tanks, or ammunition, diminishes their productivity. To say nothing of the need to rework their plants, workers have to learn how to do new things. The knowledge they used to put into their own work becomes anachronistic in part.

  For Field, the narrative history of US wartime productivity has focused almost entirely on the eventual productivity recoveries that took place, ignoring the negative shocks and losses associated with the altered product mix and the intermittently idled capacity resulting from shortages and hoarding of scarce material, components, and sometimes labor.” As he notes, “In 1948, after demobilization was more or less complete and the output mix reverted to something resembling what had prevailed in 1941, total factor productivity in manufacturing was lower than it had been before Pearl Harbor.”

  Nor, of course, can we forget the destructive nature of war: it kills people, renders others unable to work, and destroys physical capital, infrastructure, and factories. Americas greatest advantage between 1940 and 1945 was precisely that it was the country furthest from the theater of the fighting:

  Although WWII did leave the economy with assets that benefited postwar production capability, it distorted physical capital accumulation, crowding out investment in sectors of the economy not critical to the military effort. … The country achieved production success, but this was not the consequence of a productivity miracle. Between 1941 and 1948, total factor productivity declined in manufacturing and construction and, in the aggregate, grew more slowly than had been true between 1929 and 1941.

  To this, one could retort that no matter how much entrepreneurs and workers were forced to learn new things, these changes nonetheless served them well in peacetime. Fields essay patiently demonstrates in example after example that after the war, most of what was learned producing B-24s and Sherman tanks, and most of the special-purpose machine tools manufactured to facilitate their production, was scrapped, written off, or vastly reduced in value because the country stopped making most of the product. Some mischievous observers might suspect that the level of mobilization necessitated by the Cold War—albeit much smaller than that of WWII—can also be explained as a way to continue exploiting the know-how acquired in the 1940s to sustain the war industry. As Robert Higgs pointed out, in 1945 and 1946 the rapid military demobilization brought defense spending to what would remain the lowest level for the next fifty years, namely 4.3 percent of GDP (still three times the 1939 level). Between 1948 and 1989, arms spending on average weighed in at 7.5 percent of GDP. Operating somewhat like an accordion, periods of (relative) demobilization were followed by moments of remobilization, as during the Korean War, the Vietnam War, and the space wars. Field might remind us, however, that none of these phases of rearmament prepared a subsequent season of economic growth.

  If you search for it, there was certainly some innovation due to the entrepreneurial military, which then found wide civilian application (such as GPS). Against this point, however, Field reminds us of something obvious: Although some wartime innovations had applications in peace, the overriding objective of RD workers was to win the war, which in most instances meant creating or developing better, more efficient means of destroying buildings, infrastructure, machines, and raw materials, and maiming, burning and killing enemy soldiers and civilians. A key concept in economics is that of opportunity cost, which, simplified, means that the true cost of a good, service, or action is that of the most attractive alternative available. One has to consider the world to be Hegelian in order to find in the wartime economy the secret of American capitalist success.

  Wartime also starved government investment in civil infrastructure and everything in the private economy which was not deemed critical to the war effort.

  For as much as the war effort developed some technologies that were later incorporated into products made and consumed in peacetime, there are many more resources it has taken away from economic development. When it comes to human capital, “407,000 mostly prime-age males never returned” home. Field quotes Alan Milward, who wisely observed that “the only recurrent demographic phenomenon related to all or most wars is the fact that war kills many people.” When it comes to physical capital, Field acknowledges that investments in war-prioritized sectors were important and that the country in 1948 had “a vastly expanded aluminum production industry and a reduction in its industrial concentration, increased capacity in steel and magnesium, a synthetic rubber capability that had been developed basically from scratch, and the Big Inch and Little Big Inch pipelines, bringing crude oil and refined petroleum products from East Texas to the East Coast.” But wartime also starved government investment in civil infrastructure and everything in the private economy which was not deemed critical to the war effort. Manufacturing and construction were the sectors most heavily disrupted.

  Field’s chapter on RD is particularly valuable today, not least because other scholars have suggested that in areas where the greatest military investment was made during the war, the higher the registration of patents in the years following the war. Field recalls that, during the conflict, for aviation and shipbuilding, patenting rates were stable compared to those in the prewar period, but there were declines for chemicals, and even sharper declines for petroleum, rubber and plastics, instruments, fabricated metals, and other machinery, particularly when comparing 1941–48 with 1932–40. The patents that were used in war technology, Field argues, mostly date from the 1920s and 1930s.

  This is not surprising. Production takes place over time. There are adjustment costs incurred when going from producing a certain good to making another. You have to rearrange the factors of production and try to make them at least as fruitful as before. Productive innovation needs creativity as much as artistic or literary innovation. For these reasons, it is more likely that the war slowed, rather than accelerated innovations. The United States participated in WWII for less than four years: mobilization took place over 22 months. In crediting an innovation to mobilization, one must always pose the counterfactual. … What would have taken place in the absence of the war?

  For Field, despite the rampant dysfunctionality, a heavily regulated economy produced and distributed what was needed to defeat the Axis powers. War (or emergency) compresses the logic of expediency and drives one to do whatever it takes to win. The problem lies in thinking that what is sadly necessary at some times can also somehow be brought back into the category of expediency. A war economy sees, by definition, the subordination of all ends to the one goal of imposing oneself on the adversary. For this very reason, it worsens the living standards of people (who are forced to endure rationing) and the efficiency of the economy. This is why Ludwig von Mises argued that a victorious war is bad even for the victor.”

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY
John Courtney Murray and the American Civil Conversation
In John Courtney Murray and the American Civil Conversation, many different viewpoints converge and, with only a few exceptions, further Fr. Murray’s understanding of the essential need for civilized, rational discussion. All but perhaps three of the thirteen essays proceed in the spirit of Murray. The book is divided into three main sections. In the first section, essays by Richard John Neuhaus and William R. Luckey stand out. Neuhaus’ essay, from a purely stylistic point of view, is a...
Tracing the Matrix of Nationalism and Capitalism
The debate over Max Weber’s Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism has “still not gone off the boil,” wrote Anthony Giddens in 1976. It seems that Weber’s striking thesis, a quarter of a century after Giddens’s remark, has still not lost any of its steam, a fact manifested by its ability to provoke the thought and research of a scholar as able as Liah Greenfeld. Greenfeld is, as Weber was, a sociologist, and she believes that Weber was...
Environmental Virtues-and Vices
Religious writing on the environment generally fails for several specific reasons. First, most theologians and religious ethicists do not have a gift for science. Environmental science is especially hard because it requires, at a minimum, a good grasp of chemistry, physics, geology, and various subdivisions of biology. The scientist who can keep all the environmental balls in the air simultaneously is already a rare bird; but the theologian who can successfully apply his religious knowledge to a very different...
After Ideology
The book asserts that modernity has reached a dead end that is the inevitable result of its own inner logic. That logic is best described as revolt against God. Here, Walsh’s debt to Eric Voeglin is evident. The modern revolt, Walsh argues, has its origins in the Gnostic claim that humans can, through a secret gnosis and an act of their own, transform themselves into the Divine. That Gnostic quest has lived on in various forms in the West,...
With Liberty and Justice for Whom?
Gay identifies three distinct positions on capitalism among evangelicals: those held by the evangelical left, right, and center. Each of their positions are treated with utmost fairness, a feat which by itself makes the book, and Gay himself, worthy of high praise. Many of the criticisms raised against capitalism by the evangelical left are familiar, and not unlike those raised by the secular left. In addition, evangelicals on the left raise a number of biblically based criticisms of capitalism,...
Rising to the Challenge of Modern Capitalism (Or Not)
What is the relationship between Christianity and the modern world? Is the spirit of capitalism fundamentally patible with the requirements of charity that were first formulated in the New Testament? While these have always been important questions for Christians, they have taken on a renewed sense of urgency. The recent terrorist attacks on New York and Washington forcefully reminded Americans that they cannot escape the question of the relationship between God and politics. On that day, the most economically...
Adam Smith in His Time and Ours
Let me resolve this paradox by stating that Jerry Muller is a Professor of History at the Catholic University of America. He has written a book which economists and libertarians ought to read. It is also written in such a style that the general reader can derive great benefit from it. The book deftly summarizes a mass of scholarship from many different areas–political philosophy, ethics, psychology, history, and literature–without trivializing it into bland encyclopedic entries. The author sheds light...
The Church and the Revolution
What Weigel calls the “Standard Account” gives primary credit for the Revolution of 1989 to former Soviet leader Mikhail Gorbachev. Advocates of this interpretation argue that two tenets of Gorbachev’s policy proved to be the conditions sine qua non for the eventual success of the Revolution: the Soviet army would no longer intervene when its allies chose to go their own way and the Soviet party would no longer demand munist control of central and eastern Europe. While conceding...
Freedom Undone in the Court
There I sat, blinking under the fluorescent lights in the auditorium style classroom during my constitutional law class. I had gone to law school because I wanted to learn how to be a lawyer. I wanted to learn how to “think like a lawyer.” That's what all the marketing brochures from the admissions offices in law schools all over the country promise ing students. I didn't know exactly what it meant to think like a lawyer. I assumed I...
The Social Crisis of Our Time
Those who, like the Swiss economist Wilhelm Röepke, dislike both a laissez faire economy and a planned or state-manipulated one usually hope for a “Third Way” skirting both. Originally published in 1942, this thoughtful, richly textured work is Röepke’s first formulation of the “Third Way.” Röepke saw causes ranging from Christianity’s decline, the rise of ideology and the “cult of the colossal” to the surge in bining to produce “the social crisis of our time”: the rise of “mass...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved