Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
There Are No Alternatives to Free Market Capitalism
There Are No Alternatives to Free Market Capitalism
Sep 6, 2025 12:38 AM

Exploring Catholic social teaching in relation to economics is fine, but if we’re too open-minded about seeking a new mon good” capitalism, our brains might fall out.

Read More…

Alexander William Salter’s new book, The Political Economy of Distributism: Property, Liberty, and the Common Good, is an odd fish. It begs questions, contains numerous chapters that consist mostly of lengthy quotations, and at times seems to contradict itself, yet in the end it affirms an essential truth that we may forget from time to time, that private property is essential for political freedom. That it does so in a meandering fashion is not a mendation against reading it. In fact, I mend it—just be sure to read it with a critical eye.

Salter begins with a discussion of how many politicians mentators have reintroduced discussion of mon good into the American political discourse, particularly in how it relates to capitalism. However, in discussing the speeches of Marco Rubio and the works of Patrick Deneen and Adrian Vermeule and then connecting them to older strains of thought that form the meat of the book, Salter engages in serial assumptions that amount to question begging. First, mon good capitalism is worth distinguishing from capitalism itself. Secondly, that Catholic social teaching is the best place to look mon good capitalism. Thirdly, that the school of political economy briefly popular in Britain in the 1920s and ’30s, distributism, patible mon good capitalism.

To tackle these in reverse order: Distributism is explained by Salter with extensive reference to the works of the Anglo-French politician and writer Hilaire Belloc, and the great novelist, poet, and thinker G.K. Chesterton, who together provided the intellectual core of the distributist philosophy. Their professed position was that they were neither capitalist nor collectivist, representing instead a Third Way.

This third position led to some unfortunate associations. When I was a student debater in the 1980s, I visited the Glasgow University Union, whose parliamentary debate system recognized six political groupings, of which one was still distributist. When I asked my host what this party represented, never having heard the term before, he replied, “Non-racist fascists.” Belloc is still regarded with significant distaste in his native France. It takes until the penultimate footnote of the book for Salter to acknowledge this problem. My own impressions of Belloc are rather more favorable: he was an excellent president of the Oxford Union in the 1890s (when he was regularly characterized as a socialist).

As an aside, Salter really needs to learn the art of paraphrasing. He relies on extensive quotations from these men’s works, taking up almost 100 pages of the 220-page book. This es a serious problem with Chesterton, as florid a writer as es, whose flourishes therefore suffer from being quoted shorn of their surroundings.

Those hundred pages thereby e quite a slog, especially as Salter understandably pauses to point out where their economics is lacking, simply wrong, or in some cases just plain nuts. While Salter should mended for his forthrightness in these cases, it distracts from his argument that distributism has important insights that we need to pay attention to. These amount, I think it is fair to say, to the following: that private property is essential to political liberty and that es with a “political externality” in terms of costs to political liberty that we ought to think about ways to address. This could probably have been summarized in far fewer pages.

The second assumption is best illustrated by a long discussion that takes up another third of the book—that of the works of the German thinker Wilhelm Roepke, a Lutheran who represents the ordoliberal philosophy that helped Germany recover from the depredations of Nazism. Salter argues, with some evidence, that Roepke was influenced by distributism and was a proponent of Catholic social theory. However, the word Catholic barely appears in the chapters about Roepke, and his economics, of which Salter plainly and rightly approves, are far different from the error-strewn economics of the distributists. So while much is made of Belloc and Chesterton’s Catholicism, their economic thought is derided, but in contrast the influence of Catholicism on Roepke’s correct ordoliberalism is left understated. There’s a strong case to be made, as Samuel Gregg has shown, that Roepke was both influenced by and criticized Catholic social teaching, but Salter oddly fails to make it.

Finally, in his obvious approval of Roepke’s economics, Salter shows how weak the case is mon good capitalism is in any appreciable sense different from free market economics as generally understood. For instance, Salter makes much of the idea that the state has a role to play as guardian petition through antitrust law, but Roepke makes the case, as do virtually all free market economists, that monopoly is almost always the creation of the state. petition is part of mon good, and I think Salter shows that is, then surely the first duty of mon good government is to remove the barriers petition that regulation and protectionism erect. That is exactly what traditional free market economics would suggest as well.

So how mon good capitalism differentiate itself from traditional free market capitalism? Salter’s first and most important insight from his review of distributism and Roepke is that private property is essential for political liberty. mon good capitalism should emphasize property rights at its core. Yet even here, there is little difference from free enterprise capitalism. The Nobel Prize–winning economist Ronald Coase emphasized that most of the problems of economic externalities were the result of badly allocated property rights. And free market environmentalists routinely point out, for instance, that the majority of America’s land west of the Mississippi is publicly owned to the detriment of American citizens who could own and use the land.

Indeed, one of the great insights of modern free enterprise thinking is Hernando de Soto’s idea of the mystery of capital. He points out that formal land titling enables people in the developing world to utilize that title as a source of capital. Traditional societies where all land is owned by the chief and corrupt polities that confuse land titling are equally guilty of removing this source of capital from the people. We should therefore always be looking for policies that enable access to capital—even for the landless. People as old as I am might remember that one of Margaret Thatcher’s most successful policies was to allow tenants to buy their state-owned “council houses.” But if Mrs. Thatcher was a distributist, I’m a Dutchman.

As for the political externalities of capitalism, perhaps Salter is right that political liberty is worth paying a premium for. However, maybe we should try other things first. Hayek himself, for instance, argued that we need to strengthen the property rights of owners of corporations as a form of discipline on corporate management back in 1960. Part of his suggestion was a ban on corporations voting on other corporations’ shareholder resolutions. This would do a great deal to lessen the power of activist corporations like Blackrock that use their economic power to influence corporations to intrude into the political space and crowd out individual political liberty.

The non-economic contributions of the distributists and Roepke are probably more important here. Political liberty, they agree, requires a strong moral consensus among the people and a government that backs that up. As Roepke said, free enterprise requires

a general acceptance of such norms of conduct as willingness to abide by the rules of the game and to respect the rights of others, to maintain professional integrity and professional pride, and to avoid deceit, corruption, and the manipulation of the power of the state for personal selfish ends.

This is, of course, right, and it is not something economics alone can plish. It reflects something Edmund Burke said: “Men are qualified for civil liberty in exact proportion to their disposition to put moral chains upon their own appetites.” Burke was in turn a great friend and admirer of the father of modern capitalism, Adam Smith.

In his dissection of the bad economic arguments of Belloc and Chesterton, and his drawing to our attention the good economics of Wilhelm Roepke, Salter does us a great service. When we hear modern voices echo the policies, if not the arguments, of the distributists, we should remember that however good their policies sound, they won’t work. Instead, if we want mon good capitalism, we should look more to ordoliberalism than to distributism.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
Religious Repression and Economic Opportunity in the Middle East
This past weekend, Christians around the memorated the passion and resurrection of Jesus Christ. It is interesting to ponder how Easter was celebrated in the Middle East, the birthplace of Christianity and the region in which these very events unfolded. There is one factor, however, that may have made the liturgical festivities less expansive and well-attended than one might imagine: the minimal number of Christians in the region. In the Middle East, the number of Christians has dwindled to less...
Environmental Consciousness and Authentic Spiritual Practice
Beware of “environmental consciousness” masquerading as authentic spiritual practice, says Fr. Michael Butler and Prof. Andrew Morriss in this week’s Acton Commentary: It is important to clarify the Church’s teaching on asceticism because many voices in the environmental movement encourage a kind of ascetical lifestyle in the name of “ethical consumption.” Orthodox writers on the environment are not immune to the temptation of putting the ascetical tradition of the Church in the service of another agenda. For example, the conclusion...
Educational Research Just Might Be Killing Education
Perhaps you’ve seen this: the 8th grade test from Bullitt County Schools in Kentucky, circa 1912. Here are a few questions the 8th graders were expected to be able to answer: Define latitude and longitudeLocate the Erie Canal. What waters does it connect, and why is this important?How does the pare in size with other glands in the human body? Where is it located? What does it secrete?Define the following types of government: democracy, limited monarchy, absolute monarchy, republic. Give...
Explainer: What is Earth Day?
What is Earth Day? Earth Day is an annual event, celebrated on April 22, on which events are held worldwide to demonstrate support for environmental protection. It was first celebrated in 1970, the anniversary of what many consider the birth of the modern environmental movement. How did Earth Day get started? Earth Day was started by Gaylord Nelson, a U.S. Senator from Wisconsin. Nelson originally tried to bring political attention to environmental issues in 1962-63, when he convinced President Kennedy...
Earth Day and Christian stewardship
Today is Earth Day, a great opportunity for Christians to confess with the Psalmist, “The earth is the Lord’s, and everything in it, the world, and all who live in it” (Ps. 24:1). An immediate corollary to this confession that the world belongs to God is that whatever we have is entrusted to us by him. We therefore have a responsibility as stewards over those aspects of creation that we have control over, most notably our bodies, souls, and property....
How the Profit Motive Helps the Environment
On this Earth Day, says Pierre Desrochers, we should spare a thought for the profit motive, an unheralded but long-standing champion of the environment. “The search for increased profitability,” ntoes Desrochers, “has long delivered both economic and environmental improvements by promoting the evermore efficient use of material resources.” With Earth Day near (this Monday), we hear the usual annual litany of laments from environmentalists, urging us to mend the errors of our industrial ways. Greed and profits, we are told...
‘Sex Workers’ As Social Workers: A Hash Of Hollywood Idiocy
“Fading Gigolo,” a movie starring and directed by John Turturro, is apparently a sentimental look at the world of prostitution. NPR says the film keeps ” the mood light even as the filmmaker is gently tugging the plot in other directions, to look at loneliness and longing and heartbreak.” Turturro himself says that sex workers are rather like social workers (which should thrill social workers): I think there are positive things about what sex workers do. I know and consulted...
Earth Day and Asceticism
It is ing mon for theologians to mend asceticism as a more eco-friendly lifestyle, as Fr. Michael Butler and Andrew Morriss note in their recent monograph, Creation and the Heart of Man. And that, no doubt, it can be. However, as Butler and Morriss point out, it is very important, from an Orthodox perspective at least, to understand precisely what asceticism is. Rightly understood, they note, “to be ascetic is to learn to live rightly on the earth with God,...
Pope Benedict XVI And A Human Ecology
Most people don’t put “Catholic philosophy” and “ecology” in the same thought, but Pope Emeritus Benedict XVI’s writing prove that the Church has much to say about ecology. In the newly published The Garden of God: Toward a Human Ecology, the former pope’s teachings about human life, the environment and physical and social sciences are engagingly presented. According to William L. Patenaude atThe Catholic World Report: The timing of this book is particularly good. Of late, environmental scientists are escalating...
Small Business Owners Can Be Cronies Too
Politicians e cheap. To buy one’s influence you generally need deep pockets, which is why crony capitalism tends to be the domain of “big business.” But a recent article in Slate by California restaurateur Jay Porter shows that some small business owners dream of being cronies too. Cronyism occurs when an individual or organization colludes with government officials to create legislation or regulations that give them forced benefits they could not have otherwise obtained voluntarily. Those e at the expense...
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved