Home
/
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
/
Why culture matters for the economy
Why culture matters for the economy
Aug 25, 2025 3:46 PM

This article first appeared on February 24, 2020, in Law & Liberty, a project of Liberty Fund, Inc., and was republished with permission.

In many peoples’ minds, economics and economists remain locked in a world of homo economicus—the ultimate pleasure-calculator who seeks only to maximize personal satisfaction from the consumption of goods and services and whose occasional displays of seemingly altruistic behavior really only function as a means of self-satisfaction.

This conception of economics is far removed from how modern economics has functioned for a long time. The limits of the homo economicus thought experiment have always been well-understood. In recent decades, more attention has been directed to the deeper and broader motivations which drive human choice and action in economic life. To that end, many economists have begun to focus their attention on culture over the past 30 years.

In many cases, historians were ahead of economists in directing attention to culture’s significance for economic life. Almost 40 years ago, Eric L. Jones’ “The European Miracle: Environments, Economies and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia” showed how particular mindsets and patterns of behavior, formal and informal, helped medieval Europe make important economic breakthroughs which didn’t occur elsewhere. Since that time, other historians such as Niall Ferguson as well as Nobel Prize-winning economists like Douglass North and Edmund Phelps have written extensively on this and related subjects. This cultural emphasis represented a e break from the mathematical formalism that still dominates much of academic economics and, I would argue, limits and undermines its utility as an analytical technique.

Missing from these assessments of the interplay between economics and society, however, is an examination of the ways in which culture mediates—for better or worse—the workings of human rationality. In “Why Culture Matters Most,” David C. Rose seeks to develop a theory of how this occurs and why it turns out to be beneficial in some situations and not in others. In doing so, Rose takes this discussion to a new level, especially through his focus on the element of trust.

What is Culture?

“Culture” is one of those phrases that can mean everything or nothing, depending on how it is defined. The first half of Rose’s book engages in close discussion of the nature of culture and its different moral and institutional manifestations. Particular moral beliefs, he maintains, give shape to the application of human rationality. This makes all the difference between, for example, deploying our reason to realize nefarious ends and using our rationality to pursue various forms of individual munity flourishing.

At the same time, culture has an instrumental function insofar as it mitment to (or disdain for) specific moral values to be transmitted across generations, thereby establishing expectations which most people can rely upon being in place. In a culture in which social trust is widespread and part of everyone’s working assumptions about life, certain economic ways of acting (such as entrepreneurship and free exchange) e more plausible and sustainable. This trust helps incentivize individual action that promotes collective well-being.

By contrast, the workings of individual rationality in cultures in which trust is low or non-existent can, Rose observes, “undermine mon good.” Dishonesty, he says, “often pays off handsomely” in these conditions as “harm is often spread over so many people that no other individual can even notice.” Understanding the role played by culture in facilitating these types of problems helps us further understand how culture “can get around this problem better than anything else.”

Having established these foundations, Rose proceeds to unpack different dimensions of culture. The first of these he describes as “the mons.” This is “any part of culture that facilitates large-group trust” and which is “an asset to all members of society, mon cultural asset.” Cooperation features heavily here insofar as it is key to facilitating the division of labor, a point underscored by F.A. Hayek when he described capitalism as “an extended order of large-group cooperation.” For Rose, however, Hayek and others underestimated the importance of “large group trust” in sustaining markets. Trust can, according to Rose, extend further than we often realize—beyond just families and small groups.

That said, Rose underscores that the challenge faced by the mons is that it is “prone to being degraded by the very people who benefit from it.” Rationality unbound to particular moral beliefs can cause people to abuse mons. It follows that strong moral beliefs—and not just any moral beliefs—need to inform people’s choices and actions so that rationality doesn’t collapse into rationalizations of abuses of trust. Rose sees moral norms that emphasize restraint as especially important insofar as sustaining trustworthiness over the long term “requires that individuals be unwilling to undertake negative moral actions.” It’s not that Rose thinks that “moral beliefs that emphasize moral advocacy” (such as calls to be altruistic) are unimportant. They can and do, he states, help to promote overall welfare. Yet they can’t substitute for the trust-magnifying effects of ethical beliefs that stress moral restraint. These are uniquely able to promote widespread and lasting cooperation.

The Fragility of Markets and Democracy

What implications does this vision of culture have for societies that embrace markets in the economic realm and democracy in the political sphere? Following Tocqueville, Rose notes that democracy has a way of breaking down constitutional restraints on the use of state power, either through populist impulses or special interests’ pursuit of self-interested goals (or at least goals that seem to them to be in their self-interest). The breakdown of restraints corrodes the workings of markets, diminishes the rule of law, and facilitates a view of politics as focused on the ruthless pursuit of power rather than mon good. In short, it contributes to the destruction of trust itself. Once this happens, we start down the path of economic inequality (with the ing out on top), modern versions of tribalism, and the breakdown of civil society.

Bolstering the type of moral beliefs capable of sustaining trust in the context of market economies and political democracies thus es a priority. Where and how can these virtues and knowledge of moral goods be formed and transmitted in ways which can resist the pressures that flow from markets and democratic practices?

Here Rose examines the role played by the family, religion, and government in developing the type of habits and culture which effectively equip people for life in market economies and democratic polities. Interestingly, he suggests that the shift away from agriculturally-based economies towards more technologically-focused societies may have exacted a price in terms of families’ abilities to form their children in the ways of trust. Technology has, ments, mechanized many activities once undertaken by people from a young age, which helped them quickly acquire any number of the virtues typically found in often labor-intensive types of work.

Conversely, the move from the pagan world to the Christian one had positive implications for the development of trust-sustaining habits. For one thing, Christianity provided a single, universal model (Jesus of Nazareth) for living the good life, as opposed to an incoherent gaggle of gods and goddesses. Alongside this model, Christianity also proclaimed a universal moral code that the pagan religions could never have generated by themselves. These factors, along with the persistent and generally consistent transmission of this moral code across generations via the church, made the development of trust-affirming norms and institutions much easier.

As for government, Rose holds that it does contribute to mon good when it addresses genuine market failures that require a type of binding collective action. But, he cautions, if the general welfare is confused with the well-being of specific individuals and particular groups, government action risks damaging trust in democratic societies. To the extent that the general welfare is reduced to the interests of one or more groups, trust munities and individuals is gradually pulverized. It follows that any pursuit of the general welfare must be guided by general rules of conduct.

Of course, all this is much easier said than done. Tocqueville isn’t the only person to have exhibited some pessimism about the ways in which democracy could wreak havoc upon free societies by facilitating particular types of beliefs and expectations. Rose, however, is somewhat more optimistic, provided that we live in cultures that protect “freedom as a state of mind.” But those cultures also need to be characterized by “the inculcation of duty-based moral restraint.” Only then can we develop the type of culture which can sustain free markets and democracy over the long-term.

Culture does not explain everything. Economic successes and failures are attributable to more than values and institutions. But Rose has given us a book which underscores the need for more extensive work in this still relatively new field of inquiry if we want to understand more of the unseen forces shaping our economic lives as individuals and societies.

Comments
Welcome to mreligion comments! Please keep conversations courteous and on-topic. To fosterproductive and respectful conversations, you may see comments from our Community Managers.
Sign up to post
Sort by
Show More Comments
RELIGION & LIBERTY ONLINE
The FAQs: China’s ‘One-Child’ Policy
What was China’s “one-child” policy? In an attempt to limit population growth, China implemented a policy in the late 1970s that forbid families from having more than one child (there were, however, no penalties for multiple births, such as twins or triplets). Over the years, though, numerous exceptions have been allowed and by 2007 the policy only restricted 35.9 percent of the population to having one child. What is the new policy? Starting next March, a change to current family...
Housing Alone Doesn’t End Homelessness
Homelessness seems like it should be one of the most straightforward social problems to solve. The obvious solution would be to simply give people in need a place to live. Getting people off the street and into shelter is certainly be beneficial. And in the winter months it can even save lives. But does providing housing end homelessness? Unfortunately, asKevin C. Corinth explains,housing people who are homeless doesn’t necessarily reduce the number of people who are homeless over the long...
Russell Kirk and Christian Humanism
Russell Kirk Writing for the Morning Sun, Acton’s frequent contributor Bruce Walker, discusses Russell Kirk, calling him a “Christian Humanist.” Walker argues that not only was Kirk a talented writer, but he also understood other Christian humanists and was able to clarify some of their works and theories: Kirk may not have been the first, but was the scholar best able to identify [T. S.] Eliot’s nameless targets in the poem “The Hollow Men” as H.G. Wells, Bernard Shaw and...
Green America’s War on Restaurants
The network of leftist shareholder activism plex and wide-ranging. In the name of progressive causes, they panies to forfeit profitability, reduce investment returns, raise costs to customers and threaten both actual and potential jobs. It’s heartbreaking that religious shareholder groups not only willingly but passionately lend their support to secular causes promoted by US SIF: The Forum for Sustainable and Responsible Investment and Ceres. As I have noted previously, both organizations count religious shareholder groups among their respective membership rosters...
Chart of the Week: The Fragmented Federal Welfare System
The nonpartisan Congressional Research Service estimates that there are currently over 80 federal programs that provide food, housing, healthcare, job training, education, energy assistance, and cash to e Americans. How do they fit together to serve the poor? During a hearing on Tuesday about better coordinating welfare programs to serve families in need, the chairman of theHouse Ways and Means Human Resources mittee provided the following chart (click to enlarge). Confused? You’re not the only one. As Rep.Charles Boustany (R-LA)...
Yes, New York Times, for Christians Scripture Is Indeed the Rule of Law
“If any of you has a dispute with another, do you dare to take it before the ungodly for judgment instead of before the Lord’s people?” The Apostle Paul asked the church in Corinth. “Or do you not know that the Lord’s people will judge the world?” Paul continues, And if you are to judge the world, are you petent to judge trivial cases? Do you not know that we will judge angels? How much more the things of this...
Radio Free Acton: Jay Nordlinger On The Children of Monsters
Jay Nordlinger speaks at the Acton Lecture Series This week on Radio Free Acton, National Review Senior Editor Jay Nordlinger joins the podcast to talk about his latest book,Children of Monsters: An Inquiry Into the Sons and Daughters of Dictators, a book I enjoyed enough to create the “Radio Free Acton 5 Star Award of Excellence” in order to have an award to bestow upon it. Nordlinger joined us here at Acton on October 29 to deliver an Acton Lecture...
Review: That’s a Great Question
A couple of months ago Arkansas’ Secretary of State rejected the request from the Universal Society of Hinduism to erect a statue on state capitol grounds. A good friend from college, himself a Hindu, sent me an email asking me what I thought about it. What could I say? It seemed patiently unfair: Arkansas had approved a monument for the Ten Commandments on state grounds, but rejected the Hindu organization’s privately funded statue. miserated with my friend, saying only that...
Welcome to Cuba: Where doctors earn less than taxi drivers
In Cuba, taxi drivers earn far more than doctors, raking in more money in one day than a doctor will make in an entire month. The reason? Unlike most of the Cuban economy, taxi licenses are privately held and wages are not set by the state. Johnny Harris explains: Although Cuba offers fewopportunities for private enterprise — outside of itssprawling black market, that is — the number of self-employed workers has slowly grown in recent years. Seven years after Raul...
Video: Jay Nordlinger On The Children Of Monsters
On October 29th, the Acton Institute was pleased to e author and National Review Senior Editor Jay Nordlinger to the Mark Murray Auditorium as part of the 2015 Acton Lecture Series. Nordlinger’s address shared the title of his latest book,Children of Monsters:An Inquiry into the Sons and Daughters of Dictators, which examines the varied fates of the children of some of the 20th century’s most notorious dictators. We’re pleased to present the video of Nordlinger’s talk here on the PowerBlog....
Related Classification
Copyright 2023-2025 - www.mreligion.com All Rights Reserved